Background Image
Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  81 / 132 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 81 / 132 Next Page
Page Background

Cross-border

economic

development

81

Cross-cutting themes in cross-border economic development

Consequently, it is very rare for any two cross-border territories to be alike,

hence the need for informal meetings, seminars and other workshops.

Territorial authorities may seek to develop shared tools to promote

a cross-border territory

to investors, businesses and other private

economic players in cooperation with their counterparts on the other

side of the border, in a context of increased territorial competition

encouraging elected representatives to improve the positioning and

specialisation of their territory, if such a partnership is considered to

add value and create benefits on both sides of the border.

Differences in timescale

between the public sector

and the economic sphere

Public action in the area of economic development is highly fragmented

and must typically cope with a multitude of different interests, which

makes the quest for overall coherence particularly difficult.

The conflict between the long-term thinking of the public sector and

businesses’ focus on the shorter term creates additional difficulties.

This significantly reduces the chances of uniting the two approaches,

which – despite the desire for broad and inclusive economic

governance that meets the needs of businesses and territories as far

as possible – tend to conflict with, rather than complement, each other.

Consequently, it is not surprising to see the emergence of sectoral and

thematic forms of economic cross-border cooperation (which are more

consistent with the competitiveness approach) aimed at fully fostering

complementarities, the exchange of know-how and other positive

externalities between businesses, knowledge institutions and centres

of expertise in specific specialist technical areas. This is the model of

clusters, which are in the process of being established in cross-border

areas, as well as of incubators and accelerators, which can be regarded

as tools to strengthen the cross-border entrepreneurial fabric. Thus,

public action tends to build on pre-existing elements and focus its

interventions on supporting the consolidation of industrial clusters and

the strengthening of cross-border links.

Should we therefore conclude that cross-border cooperation in

the area of economic development cannot be based on the classic

institutional framework (i.e. Type I governance)?

This requires a nuanced response. While specific forms of governance

may be constructed around economic development, in the interests of

greater effectiveness or in order to remove from the general dialogue

an issue where competition between the two sides of the border may

sometimes be felt to be too prevalent, the classic institutional framework

of cross-border cooperation should not be ruled out.

It is important to stress the necessarily heterogeneous nature of

cross-border economic governance. In the kind of liberal, regulated

environment that is typically found in European countries (even in the

most economically liberal of them), public authorities intervene actively

in the field of economic development, and this intervention, which is

necessarily institutional in nature (i.e. Type I), takes place within a national

legislative and regulatory framework, as the European Union has no

competence in respect of states’ internal organisation.

A country’s public-sector players typically develop public policies

focusing on the businesses located in their territory, despite the fact

that such policies are tightly regulated by the European Union, which

encourages the opening up of borders (via limitations on state aid, etc.).

Given that policies supporting cross-border economic development focus

primarily on SMEs (as large companies naturally operate at transnational

level), action at national level may be both pragmatic and legitimate,

even from the perspective of cross-border and European integration.

Ì

Ì

Indeed, players in Austria

help Austrian businesses, both

nationally and at regional level (i.e. at the level of individual Länder),

to position themselves relative to the economic areas they are in,

which in many cases are cross-border areas. However, along those

borders, cross-border cooperation programmes (INTERREG A)

are considered too complex for businesses to participate in them

directly. Nevertheless, they can help to create an environment

conducive to cooperation, for example by encouraging the early

learning of the languages of neighbouring countries, etc. The

European Commission and a number of Member States (including

France) consider that public action, notably in the context of ETC

programmes, should go further and encourage businesses to

have projects financed through these programmes.

In fact, various configurations are possible, according to the

responses given to the following questions:

- Is the market left alone to operate in order to achieve cross-border

integration, or is there public intervention in the area of economic

development?

- Is such intervention conducted at national level (despite being directed

at the cross-border territory), or does it take place at cross-border level?

What is more, those configurations may vary depending on the

specific nature of the economic intervention (support for businesses,

jobs, etc.), making cross-border governance typical of the multi-level

model described by Hooghe and Marks,

123

where the functional and

institutional approaches (Types I and II) are in fact more complementary

than conflicting. Each cross-border territory must choose its own path

on the basis of its own partnership configurations and its own interests.

123

Liesbet Hooghe and Gary Marks,

Types of Multi-Level Governance

, Les Cahiers européens de

Sciences Po, No 03/2002

(www.cee.sciences-po.fr/erpa/docs/wp_2002_3.pdf)